Items Commented On:
Carl A. Zimring, We Ignore Our
Infrastructure at Our Peril
Andrew Ferguson: If our 16th
president were alive today, chances are he wouldn't be Barack
Obama
Ralph E. Luker, Modern
History Notes, "Dreams of Leaving,"
Ronald Findlay and Kevin
H. O'Rourke, Is Globalization Here to Stay? (Maybe, Maybe
Not),
Jeffrey N. Wasserstrom, Kentucky Fried
Globalization
Edwin Black, Hitler's
Carmaker: The Inside Story of How General Motors Helped
Mobilize the Third Reich (Part 1)
Maury Klein, "How Did the Railroads
Survive and Prosper?"
Tom Palaima, The Big Question
that Needs to Be Asked at the Presidential Debates
Jonathan Schell, The
Triumph of Fantasy Politics,, response to Peter K. Clarke
Eric Zencey, Is
Industrial Civilization a Pyramid Scheme?
Carl Abbott , Finally, Too Many Cars
Graham Russell Gao Hodges, New York
City's Latest Taxi Scam
Jonathan Dresner, How
Reagan Looks to a Teacher of World History
my comments on:
Carl A. Zimring, We Ignore Our Infrastructure at Our Peril
09/20/2010 02:21 PM
formerly http://www.hnn.us/articles/131459.html
now:
https://web.archive.org/web/20111205135536/http://www.hnn.us/articles/131459.html
Railroads, As Well.
One might add railroads to the list of important
infrastructure. For example, last June (2009), there was
a derailment in Rockford, Illinois, on the Canadian
National railroad(former Illinois Central track), involving a
train carrying more than 10,000 tons of grain alcohol
from Iowa to a refinery in Chicago, where it would
have been used as an additive to make
gasoline. There seems to have been a washout, which caused the
track to give way under the last
eighteen cars, and the resulting fire involved more than
a thousand tons of fuel. One person
was killed, others were injured, and there were
sizable evacuations from what was, after
all, potentially a Hiroshima-sized event. It could
have been far worse if it had happened in a
town center or a city, perhaps even inside Chicago. My
understanding is that local law-enforcement gave
the railroad some kind of warning that a
washout had taken place, but that the
railroad did not act on it. The question,
still unresolved, is "what did the train
dispatcher know, and when did he
know it?"
There are specialized alarms which can be built
into the track-bed to warn of derailment conditions, and to
cause them to indicate automatically in the railroad's
computerized train-dispatching system, but these
are specialized equipment and correspondingly
expensive (eg. $1000 for a very simple device, the
equivalent of a smoke detector), and one needs large
numbers of such devices, say a hundred or two hundred to
the mile, not to mention the installation
expense.
A further complicating factor was that the CEO of
Canadian National, E. Hunter Harrison, had formed the
habit of logging on to the dispatching computer from home,
late at night, and electronically looking over the
dispatchers' shoulders. He would call up the dispatching
center and start barking orders, over the telephone, at
the hapless desk man. This may well have contributed to
a mentality of "...run the trains through, hell or
high water, and never mind the Police/Fire Department
reports."
-----------------------------------------------------
Katie Backman, Matt Williams, Anna
Voelker, David Shultz and Corina Curry, "Train
derails: Woman dead; 600 families remain evacuated," Rockford
[Ill.] Register-Star, Jun 19, 2009 [ update Jun 22, 2009]
http://www.rrstar.com/news/x931198448/Rescue-teams-on-scene-of-train-derailment
[unretrievable even with wayback machine]
-----------------------------------------------------
Thomas V. Bona, "Feds’ accident report on derailment likely
early in 2011", Rockford [Ill.] Register-Star, Jun 18, 2010
http://www.rrstar.com/news/yourtown/x1501907376/Feds-accident-report-on-derailment-likely-early-in-2011
[unretrievable even with wayback machine]
-----------------------------------------------------
"Train derailment timeline," Rockford [Ill.] Register-Star,
Jun 18, 2010
http://www.rrstar.com/news/trainderailment/x1808630025/Train-derailment-timeline
[unretrievable even with wayback machine]
----------------------------------------------------
"Train derailment anniversary: Lessons from ‘the big one’,"
Rockford [Ill.] Register-Star, Jun 19, 2010
http://www.rrstar.com/news/trainderailment
[unretrievable even with wayback machine]
----------------------------------------------------
"One dead in fiery Rockford train derailment,"
Associated Press, June 20, 2009
formerly:
http://www.chicagobreakingnews.com/2009/06/rockford-train-derailment-causes-evacuations.html
now:
https://web.archive.org/web/20090625174528/http://www.chicagobreakingnews.com/2009/06/rockford-train-derailment-causes-evacuations.html
---------------------------------------------------
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/E._Hunter_Harrison
-----------------------------------------------------
My comments on:
Andrew Ferguson: If our 16th president were alive today, chances
are he wouldn't be Barack Obama
03/31/2009 09:36 PM
http://hnn.us/roundup/entries/68626.html
[no other comment but mine]
Lincoln and Technology
There is an interesting article in a recent issue of Trains
Magazine.
Peter A. Hansen, The Rail Splitter and the Railroads: Abraham
Lincoln's vision helped determine what American railroading
would become, and what kind of nation it
would serve, Trains, Feb. 2009 , pp.28-39.
Hansen talks about the fact that Lincoln was a railroad
lawyer: "Lincoln participated in suits involving 13 different
railroads, defending them 79 times and opposing them on 63
occasions." (p. 32). In the Effie Afton case of 1856,
involving a steamboat which had collided with the Rock Island
bridge across the Mississippi, with an ensuing fire which put
both out of commission, Lincoln was obliged to handle an
essentially technical negligence case. In 1859, as an
undeclared presidential candidate, he managed to have himself
briefed by Grenville M. Dodge who had been out west surveying
the route for a transcontinental railroad. In 1863,
Lincoln reestablished contact with Dodge, now a Union
brigadier-general, to consult with him about railroad
matters. Dodge eventually became the chief engineer of
the Union Pacific Railroad, with a direct line to Ulysses S.
Grant and William T. Sherman in case of difficulties. In
short, Lincoln was quite thoroughly plugged into the leading
emergent technology of his day. He was not altogether
unique in that respect. Robert E. Lee had given
engineering advice for the Rock Island Bridge prior to
its construction, and the United States Military Academy
was one of the two major sources of civil engineers in
the Early Republic, the other being the Erie Canal
project.
I cannot think of any modern national politician who is
involved with technology at anything like
Lincoln's level. Even Albert Gore has not gone much
beyond general boosterism. Considering Lincoln as a
lawyer, the closest modern parallel I can think of would
be David Boies, who, far from being a presidential candidate,
has been investigated by his state bar association.
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/David_Boies
http://www.law.com/jsp/article.jsp?id=1085069393915
[dumps to journal home page, not retrievable on wayback
machine]
Similarly, the one lawyer I can think of who has written most
intelligently about aviation is F. Lee Bailey, but of course
Bailey's reputation was primarily based on defending
gruesome killers of one kind of another, and if he had tried
to enter electoral politics, that would have come back to
haunt him.
On the contrary, one of the enduring realities of our own time
is that the major organs of government are usually dangerously
uninformed on technological matters, and tend to blindly
follow the advice of the usual lobbyists, without being able
to relate technological issues to traditional issues of public
policy. Granted, Barrack H. Obama's decisions on technological
matters are a bit better than those of John S. McCain, but one
suspects that to be mostly a matter of age, in the sense that
Obama must have formed many of his "unexamined
presuppositions" circa 1980, rather than circa 1960. We can
see this more clearly in the case of former Sen Ted Stevens,
arguably the single most misguided senator on current
technology issues, famed for his remark about "the
internet being a series of tubes," which was treated as a
general excuse among engineers to regard the Senate as a
laughing stock. The central fact about Stevens was that
he was born in 1923, and formed his "unexamined
presuppositions" circa 1940, that by 1980, he was of an age
and status at which most men do not casually learn from
their environment very much. If you have a secretary who
listens to your oral ruminations and conjectures, and
writes them up into polished drafts, you are not going to
learn to use a word processor, or to surf the internet, etc.
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Ted_Stevens
Incidentally Hansen reproduces a wickedly funny contemporary
cartoon of Lincoln sneaking through pro-south
Baltimore on his way to Washington, DC. Abe looks at
once sinister and terrified, intimidated by a yowling tomcat.
My comments on:
Ralph E. Luker, Modern History Notes, "Dreams of Leaving,"
10/07/2008 06:44 PM
formerly:
http://hnn.us/blogs/entries/55267.html
http://hnn.us/blogs/comments/55267.html#comment
now:
https://www.historynewsnetwork.org/blog/55267
[Luker’s brief notice of articles, and my comment]
Owen Hatherley, "Dreams of leaving," New Statesman, 25
September 2008. Review of:
Naked Airport by Alastair Gordon
and
Politics at the Airport Edited by Mark B
Salter
formerly:
http://www.newstatesman.com/books/2008/09/naked-airport-gordon-politics
now:
https://web.archive.org/web/20080926222209/http://www.newstatesman.com/books/2008/09/naked-airport-gordon-politics
Airports Versus Train Stations.
As a matter of physics, airplanes cannot ultimately compete
with trains for peaceable transportation. An airplane, like an
off-road vehicle such as a jeep, is a machine for going where
you haven't been properly invited. What is happening in Europe
is that railroads are in the process of driving
airplanes out. The trains are getting steadily faster,
but the airplanes cannot do so without producing sonic
booms. One recent event has been the opening of the new
Berlin train station, more or less consciously designed to be
an anti-airport.
------------------------------
Here are some recent interesting items:
Benjamin B. Bachman, "Jake's World: Visit Seattle's
gritty realm near King Street Station (Secrets of an
Urban Terminal)," Trains Magazine, March 2007. A sentimental
look at "Urban Railroad Space," the zone around an American
train station which incorporates bars, brothels, flophouses,
soup kitchens, and bail bondsmen. The pictures are all taken
in the Pacific Northwest's six-month rainy season.
R. David Read, "Reunited: And in Berlin's new Central Station,
it feels so good," Trains Magazine, September 2008. The new
station is built in the reclaimed no-mans-land of the Berlin
Wall, at the heart of the city, with trains arriving through
tunnels and on viaducts. It is a structure of five different
levels, two of them train platforms, with a shopping mall and
office space built around them. As well as the usual fast-food
franchises, it apparently contains a supermarket, presumably
for commuters shopping on their way home. However the station
also handles long-distance trains.
Scott Lothes, "Busiest Station in the World: Shinjuku Station
keeps the masses moving through Tokyo," Trains Magazine,
August 2008. People scurrying back and forth in tunnels
between gigantic buildings, in something out of a dystopian
science-fiction epic, but a couple of teenage street musicians
have "stolen" a venue, and are playing South American folk
music on the sidewalk.
Matt Van Hatten, "Continental Drifter: Uncovering Europe's
latest surprises on a three wee trip with 83 trains, 37
transit systems,and at least 50 cups of coffee," Trains
Magazine, November 2008. An overview of new projects.
I'm afraid this material is not available online, at least,
not to nonsubscribers-- Trains Magazine tends to be a bit
backwards about doing internet stuff.
My comments on:
Ronald Findlay and Kevin H. O'Rourke, Is Globalization Here to
Stay? (Maybe, Maybe Not), 02/16/2008 07:28 PM
RE:
http://hnn.us/articles/47020.html
now:
https://web.archive.org/web/20111212031542/http://hnn.us/articles/47020.html
[2 comments visible, the rest lost, mine included]
De-Globalization Does Not Mean Putting the Clock Back.
One must not make too much of European trade barriers in
the late nineteenth century. A case can be made that
they tended to be leaky. They did not put the clock
back. Their beneficiaries were still likely to be the most
relatively impoverished people in the land-- who remained
impoverished.
I think you would probably find that trade barriers to
agricultural imports in the late nineteenth century did
not include guano. Guano imports were on the order of at least
pounds per capita by the 1870's. The effect of cheap guano was
to supercharge existing European farms. Similarly, oceanic
fishing (and whaling) does not technically constitute
importing, no matter how far the fishermen range.
Steam-powered fishing trawlers were being introduced, with the
expected economies. Just before the First World War, kippers,
that is, herring fillets, were notoriously a poor man's
dinner. The inedible, or rather, unpalatable fraction of
the fish harvest was apt to get used as fertilizer; or else,
animal feed, and then fertilizer. In particular, hogs were
notoriously fed on whatever garbage was available.
Interestingly, the modern nitrate fertilizer process, invented
by the German chemist Fritz Haber, was employed during the
First World War to replace the fertilizer supplies which
had been cut off by the British Navy, in the same way
that the United States was forced to develop synthetic rubber
in the Second World War after the Japanese had overrun
Southeast Asia. It would also be worth looking
into "Liebig Extract" (sometimes called "drippings"), and
similar low-grade meat products, which might actually be
economic byproducts of leather production. Likewise, there
were early forms of agricultural mechanization. In late
nineteenth century England, stationary steam engines with
winches and cables were sometimes used to haul
agricultural implements up and down the fields.
Also, one must deal with the idea of redirected internal
trade. In the eighteenth century, the most developed
portions of Northern Europe, England and the Netherlands, were
importing foodstuffs and other raw materials such as
forest products from the more backwards areas, such as
the Baltic. Danzig, for example, was a famous
grain-exporting port. The English "Corn Laws" in the
early nineteenth century reduced imports to about ten
percent of total consumption, but that ten percent was a
safety valve in times of possible shortage or political
disorder. But of course, the Corn Laws were eventually
abolished, about the time that many continental nations were
instituting their own equivalents. The East-Elbian region of
Germany, adjoining the Baltic behind Danzig, Stettin, and
Koenigsberg, was Germany's breadbasket, but it was also the
German equivalent of the American Deep South.
German grain exports worked pretty much like American
cotton exports, that is, they were based around a system of de
jure or de facto unfree labor, in a general climate of
cultural backwardness. Once Germany was unified, the central
government provided subsidies to this conspicuously
impoverished region, but the results were generally
unsuccessful. Since the East Elbian region's habitual
market was England, there were obviously severe limits
on the extent to which it could be aided by protectionism.
Protectionism was only a consolation prize. By contrast, the
characteristic agricultural export of South Germany was named
vintage wines.
Finally, the backwards agrarian regions of the various
countries tended to produce far more than their share of
emigrants to America, thus permitting the consolidation and
rationalization of farmlands. This was most clearly visible in
Ireland, whose population fell from about nine
million just before the potato famine to about three million,
circa 1900. Perhaps a million people starved, but the rest
emigrated. It has been pointed out that in the nineteenth
century, emigration functioned as the economic equivalent of
free trade. People went where the food was, instead of the
food coming to them, and they sent back remittances as
well. This also had the effect of bypassing American
industrial tariffs.
Summing up, the effect of agricultural tariffs was not
to put the clock back, but merely to channel and shape
Globalism. European farmers tended to get first
use of agricultural imports, or the imports were directed to
low-income consumers whom the farmers did not consider prime
customers. It is significant that grain was the point of
conflict, because, given the technology of the time, grain was
about the only commodity of mass consumption which could be
shipped across an ocean, and still be a first-class commodity.
The various kinds of canned meat products, canned vegetables,
etc were obviously inferior, and fit only to make stew (*).
Eventually, the mechanization of European agriculture more or
less caught up with that of American agriculture. A type of
"Saturday farmer" emerged, with both a tractor, and an
industrial job on the weekdays. This can be seen
in its highest form in Japan, oddly enough.
(*) Of course, our modern post-scarcity mindset is that the
epicure eats an extraordinary variety of traditional poor
people's cooking: Italian Pizza, Mexican Chili, Indian Curry,
the assorted varieties of Chinese cooking, etc., etc.
To maintain the volume of international trade in the face of
improved methods of production, international trade has to be
constantly re-invented. In the 1950's salad greens were grown
in certain favored valleys of California, and special express
trains loaded at special stations in the middle of the lettuce
fields, before heading off to the east coast. By now, of
course, these favored valleys have mostly been built over with
housing developments. Fresh salad tended to be more expensive
then. I found, in an issue of Trains magazine, a collection of
reproductions of old railroad dining car advertisements. It
seems that about the middle of the twentieth
century, the salad component of the fixed-price lunch on
the premium transportation mode of the day was a glass of
tomato juice-- presumably canned or bottled. Nowadays,
that would be simply unsalable. No restaurant at the Howard
Johnson's level can get by without a salad
bar. Even allowing for a captive audience, the airlines
serve salad, not tomato juice. The green goods are often flown
in by jet from South America.
At a certain level of technological development,
manufacturing becomes trivial, ie. Arthur C. Clarke's
postulated "universal replicator." Short of that level, robots
are becoming of ever-increasing importance. If a high
tariff is placed on automobiles, Toyota will simply use more
robots at factories in America, and other Asian automakers
will follow its example. New automobile factories will be
built in places like rural Texas, not in Detroit. The firms
building the factories will be legally separate and distinct
from the American "Big Three," and, as such, will have no
obligations to the vast majority of existing American
autoworkers. What is true for automobiles is even more true
for electronics. Certain very advanced industries, notably
chemical refineries and telephone company plant, are so
automated that they can go on functioning normally
during a strike. Most of the remaining workers do things quite
remote from the production line, and the effect of
withdrawing their labor might not appear for a year or
two. In fact, it may very well be that most of the workers do
things sufficiently remote from actual production that their
economic value is conjectural rather than provable.
Automobile and electronics manufacturing, and that of kindred
manufacture, might well reach this point soon. By analogy with
agriculture, one might reach a stage where the developed
countries were self-sufficient in large classes of
manufactures, but this manufacturing did not employ more
than one percent of the labor force, and prices for
manufactured goods were correspondingly low. What could
possibly happen is that invention might fail, that new
imported goods and services might not come along to replace
the ones which are being automated out of existence.
------------------------------------------------------------------------------
formerly:
http://www.country-studies.com/peru/history-of-the-economy.html
now:
https://country-studies.com/peru/history-of-the-economy.html
-------------
The New Werner Twentieth Century Edition of the Encyclopaedia
Britannica: A Standard Work of Reference in Art, Literature,
Science, History, Geography, Commerce, Biography, Discovery
and Invention, Volume 11, Werner Company, 1907, article
on Guano
http://books.google.com/books?id=EhAEAAAAYAAJ&pg=RA1-PA207&lpg=RA1-PA207&dq=guano+imports+europe&source=web&ots=NMLMrJ5Qcl&sig=Shums-jm1qcowZJKHNRkxC5_79s
----------------
JOHN BELLAMY FOSTER, Marx's ecology in historical perspective,
Issue 96 of INTERNATIONAL SOCIALISM JOURNAL Published Winter
2002
formerly:
http://pubs.socialistreviewindex.org.uk/isj96/foster.htm
now:
https://web.archive.org/web/20030813222023/http://pubs.socialistreviewindex.org.uk/isj96/foster.htm
------------
1911 Britannica article: Fisheries.
formerly: http://encyclopedia.jrank.org/FAT_FLA/FISHERIES.html
https://www.gutenberg.org/cache/epub/35606/pg35606-images.html
----------------------------------------------------------
Hank Wangford, Cowboys: From Patagonia to the Alamo, Orion
Books 1966, extract: "We thought 'Fray Bentos' was Spanish for
corned beef: A history of El Anglo at Fray Bentos. In this
extract the author and his fellow traveller, Joe Tambien
arrive in Fray Bentos to be given a tour of the meat
processing plant, El Anglo, by Eduardo Irigoyen."
formerly :
http://myweb.tiscali.co.uk/casamirror/fray_bentos.htm
https://web.archive.org/web/20080521111522/http://myweb.tiscali.co.uk/casamirror/fray_bentos.htm
------------------------
Appleton's Annual Cyclopaedia and Register of Important Events
of the Years, D. Appleton & Company, 1900 - Argentine
Republic
http://books.google.com/books?id=mqwYAAAAIAAJ&pg=PA29&lpg=PA29&dq=imports+beef+europe+liebig&source=web&ots=l2SeqbC0pP&sig=IoXpbA7UGqvURKtoZmB07r6UjzM
----------------
Janatha Fish Meal & Oil Products,About Fish Meal
formerly:
http://www.janathafishmeal.com/pages/fishmeal.htm
https://web.archive.org/web/20080426012130/http://www.janathafishmeal.com/pages/fishmeal.htm
----------------
FOOD AND AGRICULTURE ORGANIZATION OF THE UNITED NATIONS, The
Production of Fish Meal and Oil, FAO FISHERIES TECHNICAL PAPER
- 142, Rome, 1986
https://www.fao.org/4/X6899E/X6899E00.HTM
Chapter 1, Introduction
http://www.fao.org/DOCREP/003/X6899E/X6899E02.htm
------------------------------
Chikashi TAKAHASHI, The U.S. and European market and the
emergence of traditional Japanese fish fertilizer as an export
product during the interwar period, in Socio-Economic History
Summany, Vol. 70, No. 2 [abstract only]
formerly:
http://wwwsoc.nii.ac.jp/sehs/en/seh_e/sum/sum_e702.html
https://web.archive.org/web/20050319200803/http://wwwsoc.nii.ac.jp/sehs/en/seh_e/sum/sum_e702.html
----------------------------
http://jas.fass.org/cgi/reprint/1931/1/88.pdf
[site still missing on the wayback machine ]
---------------
History of the Communities of the Peninsula
http://www.jasenbenwah.ca/piccadilly.html
https://web.archive.org/web/20080905064844/http://www.jasenbenwah.ca/piccadilly.html
in: Jasen Sylvester Benwah, compiler, Native settlements of
Newfoundland, 2005
https://web.archive.org/web/20080520035743/http://www.jasenbenwah.ca/index2.htm
------------------
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/BASF
--------------
world's Columbian Expositition of 1893, The Book of the Fair
http://columbus.iit.edu/bookfair/bftoc.html
Chapter the Thirteenth: Agriculture
http://columbus.iit.edu/bookfair/ch13.html
-------------
Mary A. M. Marks, The Corn Laws: A Popular History, A.
C. Fifield, 1908
http://books.google.com/books?hl=en&id=EwG61sjDRqkC&dq=%22corn+laws%22&printsec=frontcover&source=web&ots=WgA24peF2T&sig=k2gms8N0ax0DHA9jxNqmpR837Js
--------------------
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Corn_Laws
Properly cited and all, but makes the mistake that a quarter
is a quarter-hundredweight when a quarter of grain is
actually a quarter-chaldron, or eight bushels. For wheat, this
would be about five hundred pounds.
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Bushel
My comments on:
Jeffrey N. Wasserstrom, Kentucky Fried Globalization
Originally published 12-4-06
12/13/2006 05:55 AM
[one other comment,
not retrievable]
Misunderstandings Go Both Ways
I think one
significant cultural difference is the notion of what one
might call Ludic Production, the notion that making things is
a worthy and honorable recreation.
The patron saints
of ludic production were Louis XVI (the clockmaker) and Marie
Antoinette (the shepherdess). They had both reached the point
where consumption became absurdity. Even war, the traditional
business of kings, was no longer as serious as it had once
been. Louis XVI could not go off to Canada and fight for
Detroit, nor could he go to India, and fight for Pondicherry,
the way Louis XIV had gone and fought for Flanders a hundred
years earlier. France's major rivalry was now maritime
and global, months of travel away from Paris. The most
Louis XVI could do was to send off minor noblemen, of the
professional adventurer type, such as Lafayette, and pay their
bills. At the time, many of Louis XVI's contemporaries simply
could not understand what he was about with his
clockmaking, and he came in for a fair amount of derision. The
courtiers, busily scrambling for places, could not deal with
the idea of someone having nowhere further to go. Since the
time of Louis XVI, ludic production has become widespread in
the developed countries.
I have seen a
certain amount of anecdotal evidence to the effect that
educated Indians and Chinese, who could engage in ludic
production if they wanted to, are simply unable to comprehend
what ludic production is all about. This probably gives them
an exaggerated idea of Americans' willingness to pay for
things, and consequently, an exaggerated idea of the viability
of an economy based on exporting consumer goods to the United
States. I doubt these Indians and Chinese have any real
grasp of the social demographics of Wal-Mart. Indians and
Chinese tend to understand the United States only in material
terms, not in spiritual terms, and of course this means that
in the last analysis, they tend to misunderstand what
the United States will do and why.
One implication of
ludic production is that producer goods are also consumer
goods. The ludic producer covets "heavy iron." A steam
locomotive is heavy iron. So is a Boeing 747. So, twenty-five
years ago, was the kind of computer which filled an entire
room, say an IBM 370/3081. And so is a computerized
metal-shaping machine which can produce other machines from
blueprints. The ludic producer admires the kind of production
machinery being used by the largest corporations,
and by the government itself, and, if at all possible,
desires to own something of comparable sophistication himself.
One implication is that there is an enormous premium on
"re-inventing" expensive production machines as inexpensive
consumer goods, and this tends to drive the state of
production machines far beyond what orthodox industrial
economics would dictate. To put this in concrete terms, a
suburban householder with a houselot of an acre may very
well go out and buy a lawn tractor, costing, with all
imaginable accessories, several thousand dollars. This tractor
is powerful enough to do a tolerably efficient job of
cultivating a farm of a hundred acres, if used by a full-time
farmer. Of course, to be economically employed as a full-time
farmer in the United States, you need about a million dollars
worth of land, and in that case, you buy a much bigger
tractor.
At a certain point,
the acknowledged proprietors of the heavy iron, the
corporations and the government, find it advantageous to use
consumer production equipment. This equipment may not be as
durable as heavy iron, but it is much cheaper, and easily
replaced. This changeover point has been reached in
computers, and the result is that some of the most exemplary
and admired computer experts are fourteen-year-old boys. The
next stage of progress involves manufacturing machines. Once a
machine is successfully "ludicized," it is likely to have
costs equivalent to a human wage of about a penny an hour.
If the
machine can do a task at all, and if machine output is
considered as good as hand output by the ultimate consumer, it
is futile for the third-world producer to strive for cheaper
wages, because the machine will ultimately drive him below
literal starvation point, and that probably in
a very few years. From the third-world producer's
point of view, this is rather like dealing with a sort of
techno-jihadi, someone bent on destroying the producer for
ideological reasons, who is not open to discussion. Of course,
the promoters of technology are not actually fanatics--
they are simply Americans behaving reasonably for Americans.
There are three
well-defined types of products which account for a widely
disproportionate share of imports: automobiles, electronics,
and clothing. They each have peculiar characteristics which
prevent them from being "mass-produced fifty-year durables."
For example, a frying pan is both inexpensive, due to
mass production, and lasts practically forever,
Wal-Mart has to price its frying pans in competition with the
local Salvation Army ("Sally Ann") store. A backwards
country cannot build a viable export economy around frying
pans. What makes automobiles distinctive is that the terrific
strains of road-wear cause them to break down in a
fairly short period of time. Electronics are distinctive
for their rapid rate of technological change. Clothing is
distinctive for its extremely fragile character.
In the finer forms
of electronics manufacturing, human workers are essentially
counterproductive. Human workers breathe, and it is difficult
to prevent their breath from contaminating the product.
Hand labor is marginalized to the coarser sorts of
packaging tasks. Making electronics better inevitably means
squeezing out more human labor. Third-world countries,
such as China, try very hard to develop electronics
industries, for obvious reasons. They are willing to pay
what amounts to full tuition, and depending how shrewd they
are, they may or may not get cheated, palmed off with
something which does not give them an autonomous electronics
industry. I suspect the Vietnamese are more of "country
cousins" than the Chinese, and are more likely to get clipped.
The automobile
industry, as the premier mechanical consumer goods industry,
is in the process of increasing its electronics content, both
in the sense that automobiles contain more electronic
components and fewer mechanical ones, and also in the
sense that automobiles are manufactured with more robots and
fewer assembly-line workers. The auto industry is
chronically insolvent, which means that this modernization
takes place at a snail's pace. The attraction of moving
production to a third-world country is that the firm can just
move the machinery (not buy new), and reduce its
labor costs, without having to go through the pains of
modernization. Such a firm _can_ use the proceeds to
build highly modernized plants in a developed country, but the
nature of such firms is that they are much more likely
to spend the money on something other than industrial
investment in their core industry. Thus far, I am
speaking about automakers in their own countries of
citizenship. The Japanese firms in North American
are a special case. They labor under the disability of being
foreigners, and they are therefore obliged to carry
corporate citizenship to a level which American firms are not
obliged to match. Hence the Japanese firms go in for "extreme
automation," in one form or another. Having
produced this automation, they are under pressure to
license it to American automakers, or even to sell components
(such as engines, transmissions, etc.) based on it.
As for political
stewardship, you have to remember that there are large areas
of business which move so fast that it's a case of 100% return
on investment or nothing. Take fashion-driven clothing, for
example,-- the manufacturer times it to coincide with an
event, such as the release of a movie. Within a few weeks,
it's either sold or remaindered. Similarly, for electronics, a
production machine has to pay for itself within the year, or
it never will, what with technological obsolescence and
Moore's Law. After the premium -price window has
expired, it doesn't greatly matter from a business
standpoint who winds up in physical possession of the
manufacturing equipment. Of course, it can be argued plausibly
that Moore's Law is itself a fashion process ("My computer is
bigger and badder than your computer, you weenie, you weenie,
you weenie!"). In many cases, the manufacturing operation
performed in a third-world country is one which the
manufacturer does not expect to be performing at all, anywhere
in the world, in two or three year's time. Long-term political
considerations do not count for very much, under those
circumstances. Bear in mind that manufacturing as a whole is a
declining sector. The fact that a firm is manufacturing
in the third world implies that it does not have a
government subsidy connection in a developed country-- the
equivalent of Being Paid Not to Grow Alfalfa.
In the United
States, the military is the major agency of a certain
type of stewardship, not precisely political, in something of
the same sense that the Boy Scouts are not
precisely political. The military worries about a whole series
of things like the decline of craftsmanship. The military also
worries about economic independence. There are limits to what
the military can do, of course. It cannot impose trade
barriers, or create massive job losses in the United States,
or do anything likely to increase the price of major
consumer goods in the short run (Sematech, circa 1990, was a
major blunder). However, the military can work around the
edges. Suppose that at some point, the United States Army
decides that it is worried about the supply of
automobiles and trucks for its own use. Strictly speaking, a
rational economist might invite the military to lay down
stockpiles, but of course that is not what the military
will do. What the military will do is to push
developments in automation, especially general-purpose
automation, as distinct from the special-purpose automation
normally used on assembly lines. The military will be be
willing to back up its concerns to the tune of five or ten
billion dollars, which is not really a very large sum by
Pentagon standards. This money will be used to pioneer
things like new kinds of machine tools, much more heavily
computerized than those which are in general use at the
present, and capable of operating in a much more versatile
fashion. The military would of course operate
synergistically with the home craftsmen, and the calculatedly
respectable Japanese automakers. Jointly and severally, these
groups will present the global automobile industry with
a whole series of "offers it cannot refuse," in much the
same sense that, in the twentieth century, the
automobile industry presented the farmer with a whole
series of "offers he could not refuse." If the
automobile industry has migrated all its labor to China
anyway, then there are no real limits to the extent to which
the military-hobbyist complex can push the automobile industry
around.
All the more
desirable export industries in the third world will collapse
as fast as they arose, or at least their export markets
will. Possibly the export industries can be
adapted to the internal markets of their own
countries, possibly not.
Edwin Black, Hitler's Carmaker: The Inside Story of
How General Motors Helped Mobilize the Third Reich (Part 1)
04/27/2007 02:40 AM
and comments:
Well, Edwin
Black is not the soberest of scholars, of course-- in many
respects, he reminds me of David Noble. He has rather
overstated his case. However, there is a grain of truth within
his argument.
For example, back
in the late nineteenth and early twentieth century, there were
what were called Interurban Railroads, essentially
long-distance streetcars running between towns. Continuous
Interurban networks ran across large sections of the Midwest.
They were not built to the same standard of construction
as a mainline electric railroad, and they did not do long
distance express trains or heavy freight.
The automobile
companies did do things like buying up streetcar companies and
converting them to motor buses, but in fairness, the streetcar
companies were part of the electrical industry,
ultimately backed up by firms such as General Electric and
Westinghouse, and the electrical industry played by the
same hardball rules, eg. the Selden Patent. They had
their own racket, in short.
Electric motors
have two big comparative advantages over the internal
combustion engine. One is that they do not produce
smoke, which makes them useful in tunnels. The other advantage
is that electric motors have a lot of burst power, for
climbing hills, and accelerating rapidly. Electricity shines
either where it is necessary to go underground, or
in mountains. Of course, mountains often pose the
necessity for tunnels.
The northwestern
railroads, those running from Minneapolis to Seattle,
viz, the Northern Pacific, the Great Northern, and the
Milwaukee Road (the Chicago, Milwaukee, St. Paul and Pacific
Railroad), had to go through the worst part of the
Rockies, and then through the Cascades. They dug
themselves some long tunnels, most notably the
Cascade tunnel, and they build some tracks leading up steep
grades. Two of the three, the Great Northern and the Milwaukee
Road, employed electric locomotives, not over
their whole length, but over the difficult
portions of their lines where electrics gave special
advantages. When they eventually switched to diesel, it was
in the context of cutbacks and cost reductions, at
a time when the airlines were eviscerating the railroads'
most upscale services. The capacity of the major tunnels
is limited by smoke considerations, and in some tunnels,
the train crews are required to don gas masks before
entering.
The other notable
electric railroad in the United States is of course the
Northeast Corridor, together with its multiplicity of
connected commuter railroads, many of them electric.
Now, as to
economics, the progress of the automobile,
aviation, and petroleum industries in the twentieth
century is obviously linked to the military-industrial
complex. By 1960, American railroads were economically
moribund. Apart from the case of Europe, Russian, Swedish,
Indian, South African, and Chilean railroad practice
suggests that the United States could have gone a lot
further with electrified railroads, if they had been made a
priority.
My comments on:
Maury Klein, "How Did the Railroads Survive and Prosper?"
07/04/2011 03:00 PM
I have to
comment that Maury Klein's "How Did the Railroads
Survive and Prosper?" reads like a Union Pacific corporate
press release. I looked Maury Klein up, and discovered
that his expertise is primarily
nineteenth-century. That explains it, I suppose. I would
suggest that you read Mark W. Hemphill's "The Golden
Empire Came Crashing Down: How Could Southern
Pacific Fall So Fast" (Trains, March 2005,
pp.80-89) to get a sense of what serious work on this
subject looks like. It is also worth reading the
various autobiographical writings of Linda Grant Niemann,
who spent twenty years working for the Union
Pacific and its predecessor, the Southern Pacific, as a
train crew-member. Things look rather different when you are
standing on the ground in the mud than they do
when you are sitting in a skyscraper office.
American railroads
are not highly modernized. On the contrary, they have a
critical deficit of computerization. Maury Klein does not seem
to grasp that computers in the central office, by themselves,
tend to merely generate paper Potemkin
Villages, as in the case of Union Pacific's 1996 traffic jam,
or "meltdown." According to Linda Grant
Niemann, who was on the ground at the time, the
"meltdown" looked like classic Soviet
Stakhanovitism . That was a lesson many firms learned in the
1960's. The question to ask is how computers are
connected up at the point of application.
According to that question, the point to note is that a
freight car, costing about a hundred thousand dollars,
has no more electronics than a RFID tag. The car's brakes and
couplers have to be set up manually, meaning that
someone has to walk down a train for a mile or
more, often standing between the cars, at
risk of injury. Very few industries are quite that
backwards.
The railroads are
amenable to being technologically upgraded with
fairly small expenditures, but, given their
declining markets, they are resistant to spending
money on anything.
The freight
railroads are heavily dependent on moving very large
shipments, of at least five thousand tons. They
make their money from a handful of traffics where this is
advantageous, the most notable being coal. Similarly, they
move feed-grain, the lowest-quality agricultural
product. If a farmer should start grazing cattle
on his own land, gaining the ability to sell
the meat as "grass-fed," he would cease to be a railroad
customer. And thirdly, the railroads ship
containers from China. With the exception of the China trade,
the dominant connection of the railroads is with
declining industries, and with the lowest-value segments
of those industries.
My comments on:
HNN post, re: Tom
Palaima, The Big Question that Needs to Be Asked at the
Presidential Debates
09/28/2004 11:22 AM
The Middle East and
the American Automobile
One persistent
thing which is ignored in the whole discussion about the
war, terrorism, etc., is oil. All the stories people tell
about the Middle East devolve into lies because no one wants
to talk about oil. The largest chunk of oil (and all the
"prime cuts") is used to make gasoline. Practically all
gasoline is used to power automobiles. Solve the
automobile problem, and you solve the Middle East problem as
an incidental byproduct.
The United States
is a land-rich country. Making allowance for quality of land,
we are even more land-rich than the Russians. Most of their
vast area is Siberian tundra. Ours is the cornlands of Iowa
and Ohio. When the United States becomes dependent on mineral
resources from outside its own territory, that is a clinical
symptom of addiction. The junkie never has enough, until he
eventually kills himself with an overdose. Junkies are
notorious for holding up stores to support their "habit." Some
junkies are more dangerous than other junkies-- for
example, "meth" junkies ("speed", "crank") are more prone to
paranoid behavior than opiate junkies. Ask yourself in all
candor whether the cumulative behavior of the United States in
the Middle East, going back to Mossadeq, is not the behavior
of a junkie in paranoid mode. There was a
certain type of nineteenth-century domestic tragedy which ran
as follows: The drunken husband did not work; he beat his
wife, and molested his daughter. Eventually, the wife fed him
rat poison, putting it in his whiskey, and, being caught, was
hanged for murder. Does this not seem oddly familiar?
Oil and the Middle
East are not the only problems associated with the
automobile. Automobile accidents kill about forty thousand
Americans a year, about half of them in connections with
drunken driving-- forms of addiction cluster together. There
are all kinds of health, pollution, and ecological issues. We
need to critically examine the role of the automobile in
society. Our leaders have not reached the ability to
face the fact that we have an automobile problem. At
most, they merely want a technological quick-fix. Air
Force One is the American automobile in an almost comically
exaggerated form, and the President is in no position to tell
anyone not to drive a SUV. We need to look at the ways in
which social and organizational structures "lock-in" the
automobile. A wide range of giant buildings, such as
skyscrapers and shopping malls are practically part of the
"automobile system." If you control the excesses of the
automobile, a byproduct will be to disperse potential
terrorist targets.
My comments on:
Jonathan Schell, The Triumph of Fantasy
Politics,, response to Peter K. Clarke
10/26/2004 12:39 PM
Peoria Will React Eventually
https://www.hnn.us/article/the-triumph-of-fantasy-politics
To: Peter K. Clarke
I didn't say that the price of oil will necessarily go to
$200/barrel. I said that the Europeans could afford to bid it up
that high. The point is that the Europeans have comparative
advantage over us as oil consumers. In round numbers,
Europe and Japan have a petroleum consumption per capita which
is about half of ours. What do you do if they decide that in
view of Bush's carrying-ons, they want a five-year-supply, and
they want to build it up in the shortest possible period, and to
hell with the yanks? This is temporary of course, because once
they get their five-year-supply, they will scale back
their imports to normal levels. The European already has a car
that gets 40 mpg, and presumably his government will lean on the
local automakers to make them provide hybrid power conversion
kits, for 60 mpg. That said, a barrel of oil, yielding thirty
gallons of gasoline or diesel, is about 900 miles of
driving for them, or 225 round trips to a commuter rail station
two miles distant. On that basis, $200 is not an unreasonable
sum to pay. The average American adult/licensed driver uses
something like six hundred gallons of gasoline a year, and his
public transportation fallback is a bus which is much slower.
You know the poker expression, "buying the pot"? Well, the
Europeans can afford to buy the pot, that's all. They aren't
poor cousins any more. To the extent that Europe acts in
unison, it is a richer and more powerful country than the
United States.
The Amtrak North-East Corridor, the Long Island Railroad,
and the New York Subway System are generally conceded to
be the best American passenger railroads in their respective
categories. However, by European standards, they are
merely mediocre. As a French train salesman said rather huffily
to Amtrak officials, "you haven't _got_ any track good
enough to do justice to our best equipment." Europe has
been spending money on its trains for the past fifty years.
Check out the St. Gotthard Base Tunnel project. A total of
sixty miles of tunnels, the main tunnel thirty miles long, it
will go under the Alps without going up at all. Not only are
European cars more efficient-- the Europeans are far less
dependent on them.
Objects the size of a fuel refinery take a long time to build,
just as ships do. We might be talking about a couple of
years to build a tar sands or shale oil extraction plant. This
kind of equipment is not made on an assembly line. It is all
very well to talk about elasticities like an economist, but
actual production scheduling works out to PERT/CPM charts, ie.
who cannot do what because he needs for someone else to do
something else first? Which specialized tools are
sufficiently scarce that they have a waiting list? For example:
a specialized trip hammer capable of making thousand-ton steel
kettles twenty feet in diameter, to cook large quantities
of chemicals in. What with CAD/CAM and all, the situation is
considerably better than it was in the 1970's. Two years
might be a tight enough window to be politically feasible.
Jimmy Carter' problem was that by 1980, he still had nothing in
the way of tangible results to show for his energy
initiatives. He needed more like ten years, and he didn't have
it.
I don't know if you are old enough to have usable memories of
the 1970's oil crisis. There was a period of several years of
confusion while the elasticities were sorting themselves out.
People who started the game better prepared were able to achieve
lasting advantage. The Japanese automakers arrived in
America with the oil crisis, and they are still here. It turned
out that the American automakers literally did not know how to
make small cars, and the result was massive unemployment before
they finally learned. The Japanese are a long way ahead of the
American automakers in hybrid power, and it seems quite probable
that they will be able to mop up another sizable chunk of
business.
The Europeans never allowed themselves to get as
automobile-drunk as we did. That means that they are not going
to experience the same kind of withdrawal symptoms. They aren't
going to have the DT's. What this means in practical terms is
that the inhabitants of Peoria will simply not get enough
gasoline to continue their accustomed way of life. The
Europeans will have diverted it en route. The Peorians will be
forced to rethink things from the ground up.
What we have to work with in dealing with the energy
crisis in the United States, is a first-class
telecommunications infrastructure, built in the 1990's
with speculative capital, and now grossly underutilized.
However, that does not mean that all workers can telecommute and
everything goes on as usual. Whole classes of jobs will
simply disappear. Once a given job becomes telecommutable, the
question will arise: why not telecommute it all the way to
India? Or why not automate it? Or why not reorganize in
such a way as to make it unnecessary? For example, the airlines
are on the verge of economic collapse. They were organized to
facilitate business travel, not to enable people to go and see
their grandchildren. That said, there is really no way that the
airlines can cope with the acceleration of business to internet
time. Important gaps may emerge between "have's and have-not's,"
that is, between people who are enriched by the internet,
and people who are impoverished by the internet.
Many people who come out well in the long run will still have to
go through a year or so of chronic economic fear, unemployed and
haunting the state unemployment office and taking a
course at the community college without really believing that it
will lead to a job.
In the March 1992 Issue of Life Magazine, there is an article by
Grey Villet, "Hard Times," about the town of Red Bud, Illinois,
a town of 2900 people which made its living with a
furnace-making factory which employed 800 people directly, and
another 1200 via suppliers and subcontractors. The new
owner of the factory, a Canadian multinational,
closed them down in the fall of 1991. Some of the employees were
still in Saudi Arabia as reservists, and their bitterness
was indescribable. A decade later, the population is about 3400.
The townspeople fantasized about some new company coming in,
white knight fashion, to restart the factory, but that
apparently did not happen. No one wanted to make mass-production
consumer goods in a small town in Illinois. As near as I can
make out from the material turned up by a Google
search, some of the slack was eventually taken up by small
local machine shops growing bigger, and
selling specialized gear at longer distances. Some
of the inhabitants started commuting to St. Louis, thirty
miles away over secondary roads (a 45 minute drive, per
Villet).
Red Bud is on the border between Monroe and Randolf
counties, and I have therefore combined the election
results for these two counties.
Year Democrats
Republicans Perot
1984 9611 16351
1988 12373 13671
1992 13423
9706 5905
1996 12217
10772 2974
Wham! People in places like Peoria and Red Bud do react when the
chickens finally come home to roost. These are traditional
midwestern folk. They surely didn't vote that way because
they admired Slick Willy's morals. What the elephant
knows, he never forgets.
RE:
http://hnn.us/articles/47330.html
Industrial Civilization Is Not Oil
I think Eric Zencey misunderstands the nature of industrial
civilization. The essential resource of industrial
civilization is not energy, but human capital. Further, he
focuses on oil, which is even more of a dispensable resource.
Electricity is far more ubiquitous. There are large number
of machines which run on electricity only-- most notably
computers. Oil is a fairly minor source of electricity, and the
electric supply is within feasible reaching distance of going
zero-carbon-emissions, simply by wider adoption of technologies
which are already in widespread use. The
essential character of industrial civilization was already
established, well before large quantities of oil
came into use. Automobiles were not the first
mass-production manufacture, or even the second,
being preceded by firearms, sewing machines, watches,
phonographs, typewriters, cameras, bicycles, and a whole series
of other items. Suburbia was already in existence,
built around railroads. Even in the one field dominated by
oil, transportation, electricity plays at least a minor role,
with the potential to become much more important.
It has been noted that automobile mileage is enormously skewed,
with about a quarter of the population driving two hours a
day, for a distance of seven hundred miles a week-- in other
words, gasoline is overwhelmingly used for one specialized
activity, long-distance commuting. There is a correspondingly
large class of drivers (about 30%) who only use
automobiles for their personal convenience, and only manage to
go forty miles a week or so (*). This latter figure, one might
add, is well within the capacity of a battery-powered electric
car, without postulating any technological breakthroughs or
drastic changes in organization (**). From 1950 to 1985,
vehicle miles per capita in the United States increased
about 150%, and subsequent increases have been fairly
modest (***). The drastic growth in vehicle mileage was
not associated with industrial civilization per se, so
much as it was associated with the incipient decline
of industrial civilization, and the rise of
post-industrial civilization. A factory worker needs at least
ten times as much workspace as an office worker. Multistory
factories are not very satisfactory, on account of
the difficulties of moving material and machines in and
out. There are very definite limits about how many
factory workers one can cram together in a small space. The
classic geographical form of industrial civilization is the mill
town. An industrialist found a suitable and reasonably rural
location, set up a factory, and allocated space for worker
quarters. Often, there was an initial phase in which
the employer owned the housing, in baronial fashion, but
that soon passed. Factory workers normally lived a mile or less
from the factory-- if the workers drove to work, they did
not drive huge distances. The college town can be viewed
as a kind of survival of the mill town. Even an industrial city,
such as Detroit or Chicago, tended originally to be an
agglomeration of mill towns. In a place like Pittsburgh or
Cincinnati, this is even more explicit. There are long
strips of factories along the rivers, with their
associated railroads, and worker housing up the hillsides, and
upper-class housing at the very top of the hill.
Long-distance commuting was associated with the office worker
and the skyscraper, at a time when the factory was
declining. More specifically, it was associated with the
industrialization of the office, the breaking out of
paperwork into large numbers of specialized and/or
nondiscretionary jobs. It tended to involve people doing
jobs which could eventually be done by computers. Eventually,
bureaucratic competition, or courtiership, superseded the paper
factory, as declining businesses became progressively sclerotic.
Long distance commuting is of course not the same thing as
long distance commuting by automobile. Looking at a
table of average automobile mileage by states, and doing a
fair amount of conjecturing, I find, provisionally, that there
are certain characteristics of states which have high or low
average mileage. New Jersey, for example, is
stereotypically suburban-- it is Benjamin
Franklin's old "keg tapped at both ends."
However, New Jersey has comparatively low mileage,
reflecting the fact that so many people take
the train into New York or Philadelphia.
Characteristically high-mileage states are Texas, Georgia, and
Minnesota, the newly urbanized states. Dallas, Houston, Atlanta,
and Minneapolis are big cities with lots of big
skyscrapers, but they have outrun their public transportation
infrastructure. An electrically-powered commuter railroad, if
done right, can do things which automobiles simply cannot do,
save on a VIP basis. For example, it can penetrate into
the basements of skyscrapers, shopping malls, and airport
terminals. Compared to the parking place which the average
office worker could actually afford, anything up to a mile away,
taking a train out to a suburban station, anything up to forty
or fifty miles away, and driving from there, is an attractive
proposition.
Thus, there are not one, but two alternative models of
transportation in the United States, which work for
many people, and which involve the consumption of
minimal quantities of gasoline. Of course, with the
rise of electronic telecommunications, in the shape of the
internet, other possibilities are available. Still other
possibilities have been, from time to time, proposed, which
involve spending public money for new kinds of highways
compatible with the electric car. When one considers all the
work necessary to build a modern suburban street
(typically including electric power lines, two sets of
telecommunications cables, water, natural gas, sidewalks,
and two sets of sewers, storm and sanitary), the lack of
trolley wires or the equivalent is at the
level of a deliberate omission. We have an oil problem
largely because the appropriate corrective responses
involve public property, and the public subsidies which are
characteristic of declining industries, and, as such, these
responses cannot be much better than the quality of our
government.
-------------------------------------------------------------------------
(*) Pierre Bouvard and Jacqueline Noel, _The Arbitron
Outdoor Study: Outdoor Media Consumers and Their Crucial
Role in the Media Mix_, 2001. An advertising
research study which turned up some important results as a side
effect of its intended purpose
formerly: http://www.arbitron.com/study_a/outdoor_study.asp
new location:
https://www.truckads.com/pdf-bin/arbitronoutdoorstudy.pdf
(**) In particular, a so-called "plug-in hybrid,"
essentially an electric car with gasoline fallback, can be
used without relying on the availability of electric
charging stations away from home. Of course, this
kind of driving does not involve using very much
gasoline, so the potential savings are
minimal, and the design does not address the issues of the
kind of people who actually use a lot of gasoline.
(***), Stacy C. Davis and Susan W. Diegel, Transportation Energy
Data Book,, 22nd edition,Sept 2002, U. S. Department Of Energy,
Oak Ridge National Laboratory, Center for Transportation
Analysis. table 11-3
http://hnn.us/articles/62948.html
[the comments are gone, of course]
The Mind of the Driver.
I should like to call your attention to an interesting
discussion about kids who cannot be bothered to learn to drive,
Kevin Drum's "TEEN DRIVING....," cited below. Reduced
to essentials, in the age of the internet, driving no
longer has very much to do with freedom or adulthood.
The role of an automobile is dependent on the owner being
willing to invest himself in the skill of driving. If a
prospective automobile owner decides that driving doesn't
make sense, car payments go quite a long way in terms of taxicab
hire. If someone doesn't learn to drive in his
middle to late teens, his high-energy years, the odds of his
subsequently doing so will diminish. By his twenties, he will
have organized his life so that he does not need an automobile.
A high-school student's life is organized for him, in such
a way that he has very few good reasons, adult reasons, for
learning to drive. To go ten or twenty miles to school, he would
have to be admitted to a competitive "magnet school,"
or get permission to take college courses, or
something like that. Something, in short, which carries its own
status.
In _Rethinking America_ (1995), Hedrick Smith commented on
what he called "mid-kids," teenagers of working-class
background who were in the "general" track in high
school (non-college-prep, non-vocational-ed), and who were
working thirty hours a week in burger joints to pay for
their automobiles, including the expensive teenage drivers'
insurance. Granted that Smith was stretching his case to
make an invidious comparison with Germany and Japan, but
there was a certain core of truth in the idea that an automobile
was a focus of striving. Once teenagers decide that they
don't need cars, they decide that they don't need to
work at McDonalds, either.
I would like to extend on Carl Abbott's analogy between
automobiles and refrigerators. Kitchen appliances are related to
the skill of cooking. I find it significant that Professor Abbot
chose the refrigerator as an analogy. Other appliances would
not have worked so well. About eighty percent of
households have washing machines, but many people put their
laundry into the car at intervals, drive to a laundromat, and
use five or ten washing machines simultaneously. The twenty
percent who do not have washing machines cannot be
presumed to be a deprived class. If one looks at kitchen
appliances, the pattern is even more striking. About fifty
percent of households have dishwashers. Only about a third of
households have households have chest freezers, even
though a chest freezer is quite cheap. Within limits, paper
plates and plastic cups can substitute for a dishwasher,
especially if the emphasis is on eating utensils rather
than cooking utensils. A chest freezer is attractive to someone
who collects food, ie. buys things without any clear
idea of what they are to be used for, or when, who likes
to have all kinds of "fixings" on hand for spur-of-the-moment
experiments. In short, between a half and a third of households
have an extra thousand dollars worth of appliances above the
bare minimum, of the kinds of kind that a cook would want.
Similarly, Professor Abbott could have cited microwave
ovens, found in about ninety percent of households, but the
microwave oven has an invidious reputation as something used to
heat prepared food (*). One can take a hamburger which was
grilled over an open flame at a fast food restaurant
fifteen minutes ago and give it a quick zap in the microwave to
heat it up again. Alternatively, one can zap
prepared frozen dishes. Thus, in search of a ubiquitous
household machine, Professor Abbott is left with the
refrigerator, which, at minimum, might be no more than a place
to store cold beverages. Strikingly, a high-end refrigerator's
signature feature seems to be the ability to dispense filtered
ice water.
One of the most popular foods in America is pizza. Good pizza is
virtually impossible to cook at home-- you need the special
oven-- and consequently, there are fleets of pizza delivery
trucks roving the streets (**). We not only have a refrigerator
in every house, but we have an enormously developed sector of
fast-food restaurants, grocery stores operating in delicatessen
mode, etc. Abundant household appliances did not
necessarily lead to widespread skill in their use.
For what it is worth, there is a certain amount of anecdotal
evidence that learning to cook is something twenty-somethings
do, not teenagers. There is a strong suggestion that many girls
no longer learn to cook as teenagers, that feminism means
not growing up knowing how to cook. Young people go from home,
and Mom's cooking, to a college dormitory, and only need to
learn to cook when they get their own apartment, and possibly
not even then. Having children seems to be the transition point.
People learn to cook out of a sense that it is not proper
to feed a small child pizza and take-out hamburgers all the
time. In nutritional terms, I don't know that the issue is
that clear, of course. An increased consumption of raw salad
greens (bought pre-packaged, pre-washed, and ready-to-eat)
probably compensates for a lesser consumption of cooked
vegetables. Cauliflower, broccoli, and spinach have been
redefined as salad greens. Carrots and celery have become
"finger foods," to be consumed as snacks, without
even involving the formalities of meals. The essential quality
of salad greens is freshness, attained by daily deliveries, all
the way down the line. There has been essentially no adhesion to
the idea that every kitchen should have its own private
salad garden, to permit things to be served within minutes of
having been picked. That is only for the "foodies."' What
it comes down to is that a fast-food restaurant, or a delivering
pizza parlor, has the sheer volume to move raw salad
ingredients along fast enough to keep them fresh. However, what
we are talking about is largely notions of virtue.
A fast-food restaurant commonly has a drive-through
window. People may very well park their cars in the parking lot
afterwards and eat their food, rather than driving away
with it, but this is a solitary activity, in striking
contrast to the drive-in of the 1950's and 1960's. The normative
use of a drive-in was to show off one's "wheels," but the
normative use of a drive-through window is to collect dinner on
one's way home, take it home, and eat it at home. Major
household appliances developed in the shadow of the automobile,
as it were. The automobile created ready access to commercial
kitchens, and enabled everyone to conduct their
housekeeping as if they were living in
first-class hotels with dining rooms,
room service, valet service, etc., and
the economies of scale were such that domestic
housekeeping was uneconomic if the home-maker was
considered to be paid at even minimum-wage.
I suggest that something similar is going to
happen to the automobile, at the hands of computers,
electronics, and the internet. The roles of
the automobile will be narrowed, confined, and
circumscribed. The most obvious change, of course, will
be telecommuting. Telecommuting will be competitive,
in the sense that people will be reaching out to distances
they could not go in a business jet, let alone an
automobile, and making life difficult for anyone who won't
telecommute. Once telecommuting takes over, you don't
necessarily need one automobile per adult, only one
per household. The use of the automobile becomes a chore,
eg. going to the store with a communal
shopping list and getting everything which everyone
in the household wants. Beyond that, there is
the possibility of the transportation equivalent of a
microwave oven, an inexpensive device which doesn't necessarily
do everything, but which is capable of doing what is
necessary to hook up with remote specialists, who have
their own economies of scale, and can do things which
could not be done at the household level. Possibly,
such a device might be a better means of getting to
and from a local public transportation terminal.
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------
(*) Not exactly fair to the microwave oven, by the way, but
microwave cooking has a very definite technique of its own,
involving separate kinds of dishes, recipes, and ingredients.
It is remote from normal American tastes in something of
the same way that Chinese or Indian cooking is remote, and
indeed, adaptations of Chinese-Indian cooking make good
microwave dishes. You can use a microwave to make
cheese-mixed-vegetable curry, but you can't use it to make
first-class hamburgers and fries or pizza. Also, to cook
for a family or for company, you would need multiple microwaves,
perhaps four or six, and special wiring for them, so that
they can all operate at once without blowing a fuse. That
kind of microwave installation is rarely seen outside of a
short-order kitchen.
(**) Here's a story I heard some years ago. At the time of the
last bank crisis, back in the 1980's, the Resolution Trust
Corporation's auditors descended in force on various banks to
sort out the accounts, working all-night hours, and living
largely on take-out pizza. The left the boxes lying around, and
eventually, official notice was taken of this. A letter
was sent out from headquarters, reminded the auditors that the
bank employees still present, the ones they were dealing with,
were not guilty of bank fraud, and that eating pizza
in front of them was disrespectful. The implication was
that eating pizza was somehow akin to soldiers "amusing
themselves" with the inhabitants of a conquered town.
<
------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Some links on the cooking issue:
https://web.archive.org/web/20070906100231/http://lenz.unl.edu/wordpress/?p=33
(formerly
http://lenz.unl.edu/wordpress/?p=33)
http://www.outyourbackdoor.com/article.php?id=1077
-------------------------------------------------
http://academiccog.blogspot.com/2007/03/learning-to-cook.html
formerly
http://chowhound.chow.com/topics/284645
--------------------------------------------
http://www.independent.co.uk/news/education/education-news/teaching-pupils-to-cook-risotto-and-crumble-will-tackle-obesity-927091.html
-----------------------------------------------
http://www.allbusiness.com/retail-trade/eating-drinking-places/4174776-1.html
[no file<, not retrievable on wayback machine]
---------------------------------------------------------
http://www.washingtontimes.com/news/2008/nov/12/the-home-cooking-revival/
----------------------------------------------------------------
Household electric appliance statistics:
https://www.eia.gov/consumption/residential/data/2001/index.php?view=consumption
<<
formerly:http://www.eia.doe.gov/emeu/reps/enduse/er01_us_tab1.html
Kevin Drum, moderating, _Washington Monthly:
Political Animal_, "TEEN DRIVING...." December 2, 2004
Official version, sans comments:
http://www.washingtonmonthly.com/archives/individual/2004_12/005243.php
[removed]
cites: Shawn Hubler, "Licenses Take a Back Seat," _Los Angeles
Times_, December 02, 2004, (page A-1)
http://articles.latimes.com/2004/dec/02/entertainment/et-teens2
Archived version of _Political Animal_ thread, with comments :
http://web.archive.org/web/20041229092858/http://www.washingtonmonthly.com/archives/individual/2004_12/005243.php
This is a Wayback Machine "save" of Dec 29, 2004. Political
Animal had very poor anti-spamming security. Unlike Rick
Shenkman of HNN, Kevin Drum, who was running Political
Animal, chose, at that time, not to insist on real names, and
chose to tolerate a high degree of vituperation. His tolerance
extended to people cursing freely as long as they were saying
something. It was simply the price of engaging people who were
very inarticulate (the archetypal Ku Klux Klan member or
whatever). The last legitimate message was on Dec 4, 2004,
and the spectacularly obscene "Chinese Spambot" moved in
on Dec 6, 2004. The Spambot filled up unlocked threads with
pages and pages of links to pornographic sites in China,
catering to all known fetishes. Presumably this was one of
the reasons why the comment thread was eventually deleted in
toto.
<<
My comments on:
<<
Sinning Cab Drivers in the Hands of an Angry Internet, Who Cares
for Them No More Than For a Fly.
The overcharging scandal is apparently the first attempt to
use the GPS machinery to impose industrial discipline on the
cab drivers. Of course, if a GPS system can detect improper
setting of the fare zones after the fact, it can set the zones
correctly in the first place. For that matter, the GPS system can
quote a fare to a specified destination in advance, based on
automated map reading. That would merely mean that
taxicabs would be charging for transportation the way restaurant
charge for food-- by menu price, plus tip.
Let us go a stage further, and look at the cellphone
developers ideas for new products and services. High-end
cellphones, those fitted to receive GPS signals, which
therefore know their own location, are starting to
gain the ability to call taxicabs, with the cabfare
paid through the cellphone account. One could envision
an E-Bay-type system of bidding, in which the price of a cab
depends on the actual scarcity at that instant, and the
actual cost of a detour to pick a passenger up. The cellphone can
be fitted to function as an electronic key-- bring it within
a certain distance--say, a foot-- of an electronic sensor
mounted on a counter, door, etc; and the machines
electronically recognize each other; and the cellphone
becomes functionally a credit card. The high-end customer,
constantly on the move, does not want to walk to
a cab rank. He wants to flip open his cellphone where he is,
bring up his Rolodex, and click an address-- and the
telephone company is to do the rest, contracting for a
negotiated price with certain cab companies, and
arranging to have a cab waiting at the door when the
passenger comes outside. The customer expects to walk up to the
cab displaying his name on its rooftop advertising screen,
and the cab door is to unlock in recognition of his cellphone as
he approaches. The underlying premise of this scenario is
that the customer does not want to accumulate local
knowledge, such as the telephone numbers of
particular local taxicab companies, or the location of
particular cab ranks. At that level, the cab driver doesn't even
need to know what the passenger is paying. None of the
foregoing would be news to Michael Bloomberg, incidentally.
Of course, upscale electronics do not stay exclusive for very
long. They get cheap at a Moore's law rate. I have read some
rather weird stories recently about Chinese factory workers who
don't get enough to eat, but who do have cellphones.
That is an extreme case, but in America, essentially no one is so
poor as to be denied electronics. There will be a new kind
of taxicab customer, who calculates, to a dollar or two, what he
can afford, travels "off-peak," and doesn't even think about
giving a tip. At the same time, many of the traditional taxicab
customers will be using electronics to work from home.
What this means, with the impending demise of
the cab rank, is that the taxicab dispatcher will gain much
more power over the cab driver. Not only will he know at all
times where the cab is, and what it is doing, but he
will be in a position to feed the driver fares--
or not. The dispatcher will have a computer which
automatically posts driving directions onto the screens of
unoccupied cabs, to position them for expected demand. This
tends to make a taxicab and its medallion go further. Given
perfect information, over a distance of a hundred yards or
so, the driver can get to a customer standing on the
sidewalk faster than the customer could walk to a cab
rank. The driver will simply go where he is told, where the
machine tells him to go, with failure to follow directions
automatically logged. He will not need to know his way around
town.
Improvements in public transportation-- such as fast
trains to the airport-- tend to squeeze out the more
lucrative long-haul taxicab routes. At an
increasing number of airports, it is possible to board an
express train to the city center without leaving the
terminal building, and take a taxicab once downtown. The
same applies to regional trains such as the North-East Corridor.
My understanding is that the going rate for a New York Taxi
medallion is now about three quarters of a million
dollars. On the other side, driving an automobile is not a
rare skill. Some kind of anomaly is in effect when such a skill
commands more than minimum wage. Traditionally, a taxicab
driver had to be paid a certain proportion of the
taxicab's earnings because once he left the owner's garage,
the owner did not know where he was, and could not monitor
him. So the driver had to be given a piece of
the action. Now the owner does know where the driver
is, and what he is doing, and the pay of cab drivers will
reflect that knowledge. I understand that in Nevada
(Las Vegas) the taxicab drivers have responded to falling
earnings by trying to get themselves reclassified under the
minimum-wage laws. They will probably eventually succeed in
doing this. The courts may throw out specific clauses of minimum
wage law pertaining to cab drivers, on the grounds that the
legislator did not foresee that cab drivers would be minutely
supervised, like fast food restaurant counter help. Driving
a cab will be pretty much like working at McDonalds.
The New York cabs were compulsorily fitted with back-seat computer
terminals, GPS, and credit card readers at the end of 2007.
Apparently, as one might expect, the system involves
real-time electronic communication between the taxicab's computer
system and headquarters.
It is not particularly surprising that something
approximating the sharecropping system should be in effect.
Stacy Cowley, The Channel Wire (October 23, 2007) New York Taxi
Tech Protest Fizzles
No doubt, they can set up a techno-pan-opticon, in which the
driver is totally observed by all parties, viz, the passenger, the
cab owner, the taxicab commission, and the traffic police (for
traffic law violations).
, American car culture is changing
thanks to younger generations. But Gen Z and Millennials see
vehicle ownership much differently.
Jonathan Dresner, How Reagan Looks to a Teacher of World History
To say that Reaganomics diminished trade barriers is something of
an oversimplification. It would be more exact to say that it
diminished trade barriers between the developed countries
and the third world. Traditionally, the exports of third world
countries were confined to minerals and agricultural products
which could only be grown in a tropical climate, eg. coffee, tea,
sugar, and of course bananas. Third world countries were not
allowed, by and by large, to export cheap labor per se, either by
emigration or in the form of cheap manufactured goods.
By 1970, an extraordinary range of industrial processes had been
broken down into jobs which were done by machines, and
residual jobs which could be done by a suitably
motivated monkey, but which were actually done by members of
the developed country working class. The result was the kind
of worker Barbara Garson interviewed for her _All the Livelong
Day_ (1975)-- overqualified for his job, bored silly, but
reasonably well paid, and able to buy what he made. Over time,
such jobs grew fewer, and were confined to fewer industries.
The effect of Reaganomics was largely to shift the monkey
job to the third world. Unemployment in the developed countries
was kept within reasonable limits by the production of nonconsumer
goods, notably war materiel, under more or less de luxe working
conditions. The price of imported consumer goods fell. This
produced a lasting alteration on the class-consciousness of the
developed country working class. They stopped thinking of
themselves as working class because they were in fact no
longer working on an assembly line.
The ultimate implication of industrial progress is that there is
no longer a strong link between work and consumption. Reaganomics
succeeded because it recognized this fact.