2.
Twenty Questions On Mises, Part II: Spooky Action at a
Distance
Mon, 2006-11-27 20:15
https://web.archive.org/web/20111205025614/http://hnn.us/liberty_and_power/articles/32281
https://web.archive.org/web/20111205024804/http://hnn.us/node/32281#comments
3.
Twenty Questions On Mises, Part III:
The Stars, Like Prices...
(12/09/2006 10:34 AM)
Ration Coupons
One point you might want to deal with is wartime rationing,
and peacetime food stamps. A ration coupon is a kind of money,
but an extremely intricate kind. One thing you often find
about rationing systems is that the often have a strong
minatory and didactic content.
http://www.worldwar2exraf.co.uk/Online%20Museum/Museum%20Docs/foodration.html
http://www.nymcam.co.uk/key31c.htm
http://www.johndclare.net/wwii10_rationing_longmate.htm
http://www.google.com/search?hl=en&lr=&q=%2B%22british+restaurant%22+%2Bwar+%2Brationing&btnG=Search
========================================================================
Angus Calder, The Peoples War: Britain 1939-45,
Jonathan Cape, London, 1969
Reading Note Follows:
calder, the peoples war
This is an account of daily life in england
during the war, mostly constructed as an enormous number of
vignettes. Calder's argument is that most of the wartime
reforms were never planned by anyone, but were simply the
agregate of an infinity of individual acts of regulation or
provision designed to meet particular situations.
His treatment comes under two headings.
essentially: 1) response to the blitz, and 2) the needs of
mobilization.
The essential consequence of the blitz was that
anyone could be rendered homeless, and practically anybody
could be rendered destitute by a random act.
To put it on a more explicit basis than Calder does,
the distinction between the lower working class and homeless
and shiftless was an extraordinarily local and particularistic
thing. The best study is probably a sociological one, Family
and Kinship in East London, by Michael Young and Peter Wilmot.
They stress that a respectable family would live in a row
house or flat obtained by the wife's mother's intercession
with the estate agent who was her landlord, and the husband
worked at a job obtained by his father's intercession with his
employer, one of the small proprieters with which east london
abounded. Add to this a cetain quantity of furnishings and you
have the distinction between the two castes. All this meant
that social status could be liquidated in one bombing raid.
Obviously this was intollerable, so, as a matter
of pure self defence, there had to be an improvement in the
treatment of the most down-and-out. This turns up in the way
various schemes immediately intended to deal with problems
caused by the bombing were converted to deal with more
fundumental problems like poverty.
For example, when a particular borough in
london's east end was obliterated by bombing, the local
authorities were simply incapable of coping, so the central
government had to step in, and the cumulative result of such
interventions was that provision for the homeless became a
responsibility of the central government, instead of the local
government with its finances limited by the poverty of its
area. The effect on things like the fire service was similar.
Fire Brigades were amalgamated into a National Fire Service,
which quite apart from its superior ability to concentrate in
response to the Luftwaffe, could in peacetime deploy its
resources according to fire hazard instead of ability to pay.
Returning to purely social services, the
evacuation of women and especially children from london
illustrates the process of transformantion. On the outbreak of
war, when it was not reallized how ineffective aerial bombing
really was, the government assumed that the Luftwaffe would
stage an attack on the scale of tokyo or hiroshima. In view of
this, the initial evacuation from london was conducted in a
pell-mell fashion, with an emphasis on loading the people into
the trains and getting them out in time. The result was that
no particular care was taken to match evacuees to their hosts,
and a considerable portion of midland suburbia recieved an
unusually direct exposure to the way the other half lived, one
normally experienced only welfare workers, and which must have
contributed to the later labor victories. When it became
apparent that the bombing would be in manageable driblets,
most of the evacuees filtered back, and gradually the program
changed. It came to focus more on aiding whole families to go
to their own relatives elsewhere in the country. The remaining
part of the evacuation program proper became more concerned
with providing for war orphans and the like, gradually
becoming more like a foster parent- placement agency.
For those who it turned out would be staying in
the cities, bomb shelters were provided. The government
produced and issued shelter kits, the first of which was the
anderson shelter which could be used to create a sort of
covered foxhole in one's garden. Later the Morrison Shelter
was introduced, which could be used indoors, making it useable
for those who did not have gardens. A Morrison Shelter was
essentially a steel table with wire-mesh skirts. Insubstantial
as this was, it was enough to stop flying glass, etc, and
protect one from falling objects. Both shelters were efficient
enough against anything except a direct hit, but they were
never universal, and their social significance was even less.
In a way, one might say that the Morrison Shelter was the
perfection of non-interference, since the user did not even
have to displace his lifestyle to the semi-public zone of his
garden.
What were far more significant were the communal
shelters. A communal shelter could be roofed-over trenches in
a park, a subway station, the space under a bridge, or even an
ordinary building, such as a church. In many cases, it was
worse than useless from the point of view of objective safety.
When a shelter was struck, there were hundreds of casualties.
But even so, people flocked to them. In a manner familiar to
the readers of S. L. A. Marshall, what they found terrifying
was not so much being under fire as being alone under fire.
Increasingly, some people came to practically live in the
shelters (or absolutely, in the case of many who had been
bombed out), so the government recognized the situation, and
set about furnishing them properly. Ultimately, a shelter
would become attractive enough that the poorest people
prefered it to their own homes (not to mention the permanently
homeless). As the bombing tapered off, and rehousing programs
got under way, the bomb shelter became more and more of a
homeless person's shelter. In england, this was the
traditional role of the workhouse. But workhouses had
traditionally been run along much the same lines as jails. The
'bomb shelters' were much less punitive, since their inmates
were designated as large-scale arson victims instead of
shiftless folk who wouldn't work.
Food: the practical effect of food rationing was to implement
something approaching de-facto vegetarianism. Bread, potatos,
and other vegetables were unrationed (as a sidenote, I should
add that the conversion efficiency of most farm animals is on
the order of 10%) There were significant channels of
'off-ration' meals in the form of restaurants, including the
new low-priced government caffeterias, or 'British
Restaurants.' The authorities were primarily concerned that
the meat should be diluted in other foods, and to that end
they regulated how much could be served per meal. A range of
less popular animal products, such as fish, poultry, wild
game, and offal were also unrationed. Official spokesmen
extolled such dishes as fish and chips, which had the
advantage of being produced in britain without requiring
grazing land. The same principle applied to whole-meal bread.
Incidentally, rationing did not nearly approach enforcing
dietary equality. Even without recourse to true
black-marketeers, the better classes could generally supply
themselves as well as their social consciences would allow.
The sense is that food rationing was not meant so much to
allocate hunger, as to deal with an intensely conservative
common people, who were quite capable of starving out of pure
ignorance when they could not get their usual and customary
foods, and could not grasp that the offered substitutes were
edible, or could not successfully prepare them. The spirit of
rationing was more oriented to preventing a panic, in which
people might get hurt.
There were an extraordinary variety of
mass-participation organizations: Home Guard, ARP, auxiliary
firemen, air raid rescue, firewatchers, Women's Volunteer
Service, and so on. At first these were voluntary, but they
gradually merged into the labor direction-conscription system.
Additionally there were salvage drives (e.g. housewares for
scrap metal), and sponsorship schemes. The net effect of these
was to give practically everyone a sense of being an active
participant in the war.
Appropriate bodies were set up to run the war
economy proper, mostly consisting of self-direction by the
industry concerned. Additionally, there was a system of
directing labor which eventually became more or less
comprehensive. One significant aspect was that, under the
ex-trade-unionist labor minister Ernest Bevin, obtaining
relatively favored status within the system of priorities was
often conditional upon a firm becoming a union shop,
establishing full cooperation with the relevent trade union,
including various forms of industrial democracy (among other
things, what sounds like an early form of quality circle). The
labor unions had agreed to dilution, the temporary replacement
of skilled workers (generally men) with unskilled workers
(women and youths). In many cases this meant reorganizing the
job on a more nearly assembly line basis, but there was also
an emphasis on setting up technical school courses to supply
new skilled workers. The continual shortage of labor required
exploring more and more unconventional sources of it, such as
employing handicapped people, as well as setting up
arrangements whereby women could work at home.
(12/13/2006 05:24 AM)
(My comment)
Poll Taxes, Requisitions
Well, there is a certain amount of anthropological literature
pertaining to poll taxes in West Africa, and the so-called
"Journalero" [day laborer] system in Central America (I
cannot recall whether it was Nicaragua or Guatemala). The
basic thing you have to understand is that peasant cultivators
do not want to be in the market. They prefer to "provision the
household," that is, to produce things which they can
consume directly. So the government has to
find some means of forcing them into the market.
In the land-scarce regions of the world, such as most of Asia
and the Middle East, the government collects taxes on land, or
monopolizes the irrigation water supply (Wittvogel's
"hydraulic despotism"). Landlordism is generally a fossilized
form of tax collection, and indeed, in some cases, eg. the
Zamindar system of India, it is impossible to make a
distinction between the two. In the areas where land is
abundant (Africa. Latin America), this system of collecting
taxes on land does not work. People simply escape into
the remote jungle. The most common solution was some
form of slavery or serfdom, eg. the Spanish colonial
"encomienda." But there were other systems. West Africans were
obliged to work for wages on plantations, or make cash
crops, in order to get the money to pay the poll tax. In
the case of the Journalero system in Central America, peasants
owning less than a stipulated amount of land were
required to work for wages a certain number of days, and to
collect a receipt to that effect from their employer, to show
to the officials. With pre-industrial technology, market
transaction costs tend to outweigh efficiencies of scale, etc.
Under premodern/early modern conditions, there was an emphasis
on "customshouse taxation," that is, the government used its
limited power to collect taxes at a port, or a bridge, or the
gates of a city, rather than trying to control the hinterland,
and compensated for its limited power by levying a draconian
rate on the goods thus taxed. Thus, it simply did not make
sense to produce things for sale until one had exhausted the
possibilities of self-consumption.
You might also find it interesting to read the
eighteenth-century military theoretician, Marshal de Saxe, on
the subject of "requisitioning." His system, in occupied
territory, involved requiring village notables to come in to
headquarters and buy "Protections." A raiding party
would then go out and check if villages had "Protections." The
raiding party would move stealthily, and arrive in a
given village without warning. If the village did not have a
Protection, the raiding party would burn down a house, without
any further discussion or negotiation, and then leave, fast,
before an ambush could materialize.
Reveries on the art of war
[by] Marshal Maurice de
Saxe,translated and edited by Brig.
General Thomas R. Phillips.,
Harrisburg, Pa., The Military service publishing
company, 1944.
7.
Questions on Mises VII: A Gold Standard by Any Other Name
Thursday, December 14, 2006
https://web.archive.org/web/20111126181503/http://hnn.us/blogs/archives/4/200612?page=1
Scroll down to Dec 14, no comments saved.
8.
Questions on Mises VIII: The Paradoxical Value of Cake.
And Pennies.
December 15, 2006
http://hnn.us/blogs/comments/32993.html#comment
https://web.archive.org/web/20111126181503/http://hnn.us/blogs/archives/4/200612?page=1
Scroll down to December 15,
comments not saved.
(12/17/2006 11:27 AM)
A
Counter-Question
Here is a question of my own, if I may take the liberty of
inserting it. Has anyone within the Austrian School
done a systematic response to William Morris, in
particular to Morris's utopian novel, _News From Nowhere_
(1890). In the tradition of utopian novels, News From
Nowhere is about half Socratic dialog, and half travelogue
as illustrative example. Morris's big point was the
insight that work is fun, that creating things is fun,
or to put it in his own words, "Plenty of reward-- the
reward of creation. The wage which God gets... If you
are going to paid for the pleasure of creation, the
next thing we shall hear of will be a bill being sent in for
the begetting of children." (I should add that Morris
was referring to the natural way, "making whoopee," not to
test-tube babies and suchlike. Ch. 15, p.
274, A. L. Morton, ed., Three Works by William
Morris, 1968,4th printing, 1977).
See also the "shopping" episode in ch. 6, pp. 216-18.
In Morris's terms, if production is an innate drive, the
finer details of money and exchange are essentially
irrelevant. At present, the overwhelmingly most important
development in the political economy of technology is the
Open Source Movement, and Morris is a kind of
unacknowleged theoretician for this movement. I do
not know whether Richard M. Stallman has ever
read Morris, but he and his followers act as they
would act if they were all carrying around copies of
New From Nowhere in their pockets.
I google-searched the Von Mises Institute website, and
judging by what I found, the authors posted there
seemed to lump Morris as a "romantic," without knowing
very much of his work. They seemed rather more
aware of open-source software, but my general
impression was that they lumped it in with the free
market.
=========================================================
http://www.mises.org/
http://www.google.com/search?as_q=&hl=en&num=100&btnG=Google+Search&as_epq=+william+morris&as_oq=&as_eq=&lr=&as_ft=i&as_filetype=&as_qdr=all&as_nlo=&as_nhi=&as_occt=any&as_dt=i&as_sitesearch=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.mises.org%2F&as_rights=&safe=images
http://www.google.com/search?as_q=&hl=en&num=100&btnG=Google+Search&as_epq=news+from+nowhere&as_oq=&as_eq=&lr=&as_ft=i&as_filetype=&as_qdr=all&as_nlo=&as_nhi=&as_occt=any&as_dt=i&as_sitesearch=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.mises.org%2F&as_rights=&safe=images
As Morris would say, like the book about the snakes in
Ireland
http://www.google.com/search?as_q=&hl=en&num=100&btnG=Google+Search&as_epq=open+source&as_oq=&as_eq=&lr=&as_ft=i&as_filetype=&as_qdr=all&as_nlo=&as_nhi=&as_occt=any&as_dt=i&as_sitesearch=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.mises.org%2F&as_rights=&safe=images
The Piece of Cake Paradox, Solved?
[Apparently in lieu of Qestion IX]
December 19, 2006
https://web.archive.org/web/20111126182043/http://hnn.us/liberty_and_power/articles/33114
10.
Questions on Mises X: Now with Current Events Tie-Ins
January 5, 2007
https://web.archive.org/web/20111206192615/http://hnn.us/blogs/archives/4/200701?page=2
Scroll down to Jan 5, comments not saved.
http://hnn.us/blogs/entries/33665.html
(01/11/2007 02:19 PM)
Socially Embedded Money
Below is a quick search-list for Ithaca Hours, the most
well-established and well-documented local currency.
Ithaca Hours seem to circulate among a fairly definite
social strata, approximately the small
college-dropout-shopkeeper class in a college town.
This is a group which knows each other socially, and in any
event, would be trading among themselves on a basis not
available to the general public. The effect of the Ithaca
Hour is that, instead of negotiating "neighbor discounts" on
a case-by-case basis, they can let the discount rate
float. It is a means of regularizing their
pre-existing practice. There is probably a nontrivial
support from state-paid liberal academics whose social
position requires them to buy Ithaca Hours for dollars and
to be seen to spend them. I suspect it's a bit
like being in the local food co-op. We are
talking about socially embedded transactions. Orthodox
Jews do not eat ham and cheese sandwiches, no matter how
cheap they are. End of discussion. For a local
merchant, there are substantial economic consequences to
being part of the local "old-boy network,"
such as referral business, access to non-bank credit, etc.
At a guess, Provincetown, Mass., might have a
similar social stratigraphy. I believe that, at one point,
Kurt Vonnegut lived there. The "Dune Doubloon" might well
prove to be viable, within similar limits.
======================================
Jeffrey Jacob, Merlin Brinkerhoff, Emily Jovic and Gerald
Wheatley, The Social and Cultural Capital of Community
Currency: An Ithaca HOURS Case Study Survey
http://209.85.165.104/search?q=cache:rVSOT7nlbg8J:www.le.ac.uk/ulmc/ijccr/vol7-10/IJCCR%25208no4.pdf+%2B%22Ithaca+Hours%22+%2Bdistribution&hl=en&gl=us&ct=clnk&cd=3
http://www.le.ac.uk/ulmc/ijccr/vol7-10/IJCCR%208no4.pdf
A basic study of who trades in Ithaca Hours,
to what extent, etc.
---------------------------------------------------------
http://www.ithacahours.com/
http://www.ithacahours.org/
---------------------------------------------------------
Keith Hart, IE + IT = ED?: Is informal economy plus
information technology a path towards economic democracy?
http://www.rethinkingeconomies.org.uk/web/d/doc_29.pdf
http://72.14.209.104/search?q=cache:MwpIFXW9_-oJ:www.rethinkingeconomies.org.uk/web/d/doc_29.pdf+%2B%22Ithaca+Hours%22+%2Bkula&hl=en&gl=us&ct=clnk&cd=4
--------------------------------------------------------
http://iang.org/free_banking/boyle_fm_ithaca.html
--------------------------------------------------------
http://www.abbedon.com/electricminds/html/edg_scan_1528.html
-------------------------------------------------
http://www.motherearthnews.com/Livestock_and_Farming/1993_August_September/The_Ultimate_Barter
--------------------------------------------------
HNN post, Jason Kuznicki, Questions
on Mises X: Now with Current Events Tie-Ins
(01/11/2007 02:25 PM)
Reading note for
an analogous book
----------------------------------------
Muldrew, Craig, The economy of
obligation: the culture of credit and
social relations in early modern England (Basingstoke:
Macmillan; New York: St. Martin's press, 1998)
In the towns of late medieval England, and an undetermined
distance out into the countryside, credit worked rather like
primal honor (vide Bertram Wyatt-Brown). People of extremely
modest means were enmeshed in networks of modest borrowings
and lendings, primarily in the form of trade credit, eg. a
small cobbler who sold shoes on credit and in turn obtained
both leather (raw material) and food (personal consumption)
on credit. It was normal for almost everyone to both owe to
many people, and be owed by many people, total sums on the
same order of magnitude as their net worth or their annual
income. These debts could be continued more or less
indefinitely, provided the debtor retained the reputation of
an upright and honest man. It was only with probate that
accounts were finally settled. This system was held together
by a network of mutual trust. It was important to be seen to
be an upright man within a small face-to-face community.
This implied being seen to be a hard worker, and
simultaneously, a modest consumer. Someone who did not
behave in the approved fashion was likely to have a creditor
demand payment, whereupon other creditors would demand
payment, and in the end the debtor might be hauled off to
debtors' prison.
At the end of the sixteenth century, and the
beginning of the seventeenth, this system was breaking down.
Litigation reached an all-time high, as people began to
panic about the consequences of being linked through chains
of credit to strangers of whom they knew nothing. The rate
of imprisonment for debt also soared.
The courts eventually became the nucleus of a
new system of credit. First, they served as a mechanism of
identifying deadbeats, then lawyers became experts in
creditworthiness, and then the lawyers went into business
for themselves as "writers," ie. proto-bankers. At the
same time, the national government began to permanently fund
its debt, and this became a locus for investment. In the
long run, government paper became the medium of exchange,
allowing individuals to simplify their finances.
This book has a solid core of statistical
evidence (tax, probate, and court records, or one sort or
another) from King's Lynn, in Norfolk, but it is fleshed out
by statistics from other towns, and anecdotal sources from
all over England.
Questions on Mises XI: A Stumbling
Block
January 10, 2007
https://web.archive.org/web/20111206204524/http://hnn.us/blogs/archives/4/200701?page=1
Scroll down to Jan 10